On the UN General Assembly Voting System.

The United Nations General Assembly’s one-country-one-vote system faces criticism for underrepresenting major world powers while giving tiny nations disproportionate influence.

Is there a better way? Let’s look into it.

As usual, it is good to start at the start.

The United Nations General Assembly (UNGA) is one of the six principal organs established in the UN Charter in 1945, serving as the main deliberative and policymaking body of the United Nations. Comprising all 193 member states of the UN, the General Assembly provides a unique forum for multilateral discussion on a broad range of international issues covered by the Charter.

Throughout its history, the General Assembly has played a key role in addressing issues related to peace and security, economic development, decolonization, human rights, health, education, culture and the environment. While the Assembly cannot force action by any state, its recommendations have strong moral and political authority reflecting the ideals and aspirations of humanity.

The General Assembly sets the agenda and budget for the UN, elects members to other UN bodies, and admits new members upon recommendation from the Security Council. While the Security Council is responsible for enforcing decisions and addressing threats to peace, the General Assembly makes recommendations through resolutions agreed upon by majority or two-thirds vote of its members — depending on the topic at hand.

The universal nature and large membership of the General Assembly lends it legitimacy in representing the interests of people around the world. However, its large size also leads to challenges in reaching consensus. The structure of the voting system, where each member state receives one equal vote, is also open to some rather obvious criticism: It underrepresents populous countries and over-empowers small states.

However, proposals to reform UN voting around metrics like GDP or population also carry risks and challenges. Core issues include balancing democratic representation for individuals versus state sovereignty, preventing any states from being marginalised or dominant, and finding compromises between competing interests in any multilateral body.

The logic behind the current one-country-one-vote system for decision-making in the General Assembly follows the principle of the sovereign equality of all member states. However, this means that countries with tiny populations such as Tuvalu (11,000), Nauru (10,800), Palau (18,000), and San Marino (33,500), have the same voting power as larger countries such as China (1.4 Billion), India (1.38 Billion), United States (331 Million), Indonesia (273 Million), Pakistan (220 Million), and Brazil (212 Million).

This means that countries with larger populations have their interests underrepresented relative to smaller countries.

Citizens of populous countries like China, India, and the United States have less voting power per capita compared to citizens of smaller countries. For example, each person in India has around 1/1.4 billionth of India’s vote, while each Tuvaluan has around 1/11,000th of Tuvalu’s vote. So a Tuvaluan’s UN vote is nearly 100,000 times more influential than an Indian’s vote when considering per capita voting power. This, one could argue, distorts democratic representation as the will of India’s 1.4 billion people equals the will of Tuvalu’s 11,000 people in the UN General Assembly.

So why is this?

What’s the argument for running the voting mechanism in this way?

While the current voting structure results in unequal representation on a per capita basis, upholding the sovereign equality of all UN member states is a fundamental principle that should be protected. The UN is an association of sovereign countries, not a directly democratic parliament representing individual people.

The one-country-one-vote system adheres to the UN Charter’s affirmation of the equal rights of nations large and small. Denying the equality of states would undermine the organisations legitimacy and purpose. Population size should not determine influence, as this would lead to a tyranny of the most populous countries over smaller ones. The issues deliberated at the UN, like human rights and disarmament, affect all countries equally regardless of size.

After all, China and India together account for around 36% of the world’s total population. This means that they could easily pressure a few other countries to reach the 50% mark on most decisions in the General Assembly, if this was done purely on population size.

This would undermine the UN’s mission to be inclusive of all sovereign member states, effectively silencing the voices of smaller nations on the world stage. It could breed resentment from other regions like Africa, Europe, and the Americas whose perspectives and challenges would be discounted under the demographic weight of China and India. Rigid voting blocs could emerge that undermine cooperation and legitimacy. While imperfect, the current one-country-one-vote system upholds the UN philosophy of giving equal representation to all countries regardless of population. Moving to a purely population-based allocation would divide the General Assembly and empower just two countries to dominate the global agenda based on their sheer numbers rather than fairness and consensus.

Priorities around island vulnerability, rainforest conservation, development needs of landlocked nations, and more could be sidelined. Focus might shift heavily toward Asian security matters at the expense of other regions. Long-standing alliances like the African Union may fracture if members diverge between siding with China/India versus resisting their influence. There is also risk of exacerbating tensions between these demographic giants if they leverage their combined votes for national interests over global ones. And if additional populous nations then aligned with them, it could create entrenched and polarised factions undermining the UN’s mandate to foster cooperation.

It would also create some perverse incentives. Transitioning to a purely population-based voting system in the UN General Assembly could perversely incentivise unsustainable population growth as a pathway for countries to increase their global influence. Without the equalising effect of one-country-one-vote, states may aggressively pursue higher birth rates through policies discouraging family planning, women’s empowerment and education. Population size could be prioritised over real human development, as authoritarian regimes see growing numbers as a route to more power in the UN. It could disincentivize controlling diseases, establishing sustainable development, and avoiding environmental crises, instead accelerating unsustainable growth. Basing UN voting power exclusively on population risks creating a dangerous mentality of demographic arms races and rewards for failing to improve living standards for citizens.

However, this does not mean that we should not consider any alternative ways to look at how the General Assembly voting system works. There are already some examples within the UN system of using weighted voting as an alternative model, such as the approach taken by the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and World Bank.

The IMF and World Bank both have weighted voting systems that allocate power based on the economic and financial strength of member nations. Each IMF member country is assigned a quota that represents its financial commitment and broadly aligns with the size of its economy, with this quota determining its number of votes and influence. Similarly, in the World Bank votes are distributed according to a formula where each country gets a minimum number of votes plus additional votes proportional to their capital subscription. This means major advanced economies like the United States, with large financial commitments and capital subscriptions, are allocated dominant voting shares of around 16% in both institutions. Meanwhile, developing countries have much smaller shares typically around 0.1% of the vote. This weighted distribution concentrates decision-making power in the IMF and World Bank among the largest and wealthiest economies. It contrasts sharply with the one-country-one-vote system for United Nations General Assembly resolutions, which removes voting power from economic calculations in order to give equal representation to all member states regardless of size or wealth.

One potential alternative to the current one-country-one-vote system would be a blended voting structure where the 193 General Assembly votes are allocated through three weighted components. First, each UN member state would receive one standard vote, maintaining the basic principle of equal representation for all countries. Second, additional votes would be allocated based on each country’s percentage share of global GDP, incorporating relative economic strength. Finally, votes would also be weighted based on each country’s percentage of total world population, reflecting demographic realities. Under this model, the 193 General Assembly votes would be distributed through a combination of a guaranteed minimum vote per state plus weighted calculations based on economic and population factors.

Allocating Assembly votes through standard membership, GDP, and population could offer several advantages. The standard vote per state maintains equal representation as a basic principle. Factoring in GDP and population better aligns voting influence with global economic and demographic realities, increasing buy-in from major underrepresented economies. The blended structure strikes a compromise between competing fairness concepts – equality of states and size-based power. Rather than a direct population model that risks bloc dominance by highly populous nations, this 3-part system incorporates different metrics to balance interests. Small states keep membership-based parity protection while larger ones gain influence proportional to economic and population weight. By distributing power across different attributes, a hybrid weighted approach could strengthen representation for all countries versus pure equality or population. The multi-factor vote allocation aims to be an improvement that balances without disenfranchising different UN member groupings and interests.

However, this would not be without its share of challenges.

Implementing a blended voting system with multiple weighted components would add logistical complexity versus the current simple one-country-one-vote approach. Determining the precise formula for allocating votes across membership, GDP, and population would require difficult negotiations and agreement. The complexity extends to regular recalculation of voting shares as economic and demographic data changes over time.

Getting consensus from all UN member states on the exact ratios and weightings between the three vote components would prove challenging. Countries would likely debate endlessly based on self-interest, preventing agreement on allocation calculations. This difficulty reaching compromise risks delaying any voting reform.

Furthermore, basing any portion of votes on GDP opens the door to potential data distortion, as countries could have incentives to inflate their GDP to boost influence. There is risk of deliberate manipulation of statistics, favorable methodologies, fabricated data, and resistance to revisions that hurt standing. Rigorous verification processes would be needed to audit GDP data used for vote calculations. Standards set by neutral bodies could help, along with transparency, anti-fraud measures, and consistent estimating approaches resistant to political pressure. Without careful guardrails, incorporating GDP into voting formulas risks corrupting the integrity of economic data. Yet developing foolproof safeguards poses its own complex challenges. This additional layer of controversy around GDP figures would further complicate negotiations already prone to endless debate based on national self-interest.

And despite blending factors, there is still some chance of misrepresentation under this system. Small countries may still be slightly overrepresented relative to their global impact. Meanwhile, populous nations could argue their demographic weight is underserved and be dissatisfied with the compromise.

Basing some votes on GDP risks emerging economic powers like China, India, and Brazil gaining disproportionate influence as their share of global GDP rises. Their growing economic strength would translate into greater voting power under this system.

There are risks that a blended voting system could solidify the current world order in a way that makes it difficult for developing nations to gain more influence down the line. Basing a portion of votes on GDP and population could bake in the existing hierarchies where advanced economies like the US, China, and Europe dominate based on the size of their economies and populations today. This means emerging economies may find it harder to translate their future growth into commensurate voting power, as the formulas codify a status quo that favors incumbents. Changes in economic and demographic power could fail to be reflected in UN voting dynamics due to the inertia of the blended system. Some nations fear vocalizing this concern lest it seem they are currently undeserving of influence, but the risk of permanent calcification of the current world order remains unless reform is undertaken with long-term power shifts in mind. Proponents of blended voting will need to consider ways to make any new system adaptable to changing realities.

Let’s look at some other potential ways of doing this.

One proposed reform is a graduated voting scale where countries are allocated between 1-10 Assembly votes based on factors like GDP, population, and UN financial contributions. A graduated voting system was actually proposed at the 1945 conference that created the UN Charter.

Proponents argue this could help differentiate voting power to some degree without fully overhauling the system. Awarding more votes to major economies may increase their buy-in and acceptance of diluted external power within the UN. Small states would retain a minimum level of representation through one guaranteed vote. A graduated scale also theoretically allows incremental shifts in line with changing global dynamics.

However, a graduated voting system also faces substantial critiques. Determining the precise criteria and vote allocation formula could prove highly contentious, with endless debates on thresholds and categories. Once set, the grading scale could become very rigid and fail to reflect evolving power balances over time. Cut-off points may seem arbitrary, for instance with a country rated 6 voicing valid concerns about proximity to one rated 5 in votes. The complexity of calculating votes based on multiple shifting factors also reduces predictability for member states. Additionally, feasibility concerns persist given the failed attempt to implement graduated voting in 1945.

With thoughtful implementation, it could refine General Assembly voting to be more responsive to the UN’s evolving membership and purpose. On balance, a graduated voting scale offers a hybrid model between pure equality and straight population/economic dominance. However, practical challenges around feasibility, rigidity, and arbitrary thresholds may undermine its strengths. Careful design and weighting of factors could mitigate some negatives, but graduated voting remains an imperfect solution. While no model is perfect, this approach illustrates the difficulties in balancing interests within any reformed UN voting structure.

My feeling about this proposed solution is that it feels very “UN” — i.e. rather complex, open to endless debate, and nobody ends up happy in the end.

Allocating a portion of General Assembly seats to geographic regions could better incorporate regional interests and perspectives into decision-making. Representation by region rather than individual state may also streamline and consolidate voting blocs. However, determining the allocation of regional seats raises thorny questions over which nations belong to which bloc. Regions themselves are diverse with conflicting priorities. Individual small states may resent handing their voice to a broader region in which they get drowned out. But if done thoughtfully, some regional representation could add a helpful wider lens to Assembly deliberations.

Regional representation offers some benefits but faces complex implementation issues regarding bloc allocation. Another proposal that reimagines General Assembly structure is a two-house system.

Establishing an upper house weighted by GDP/population and a lower house based on equal representation could require compromise between the big and small powers. An upper house gives major economies influence commensurate with global stature, while equal voting in the lower house preserves small states’ interests. However, reaching agreement on precise structures and voting thresholds poses challenges. The two houses could frequently become deadlocked on resolutions. Questions also arise over how to resolve conflicts between the chambers. Yet a two-house system could potentially strike an internal bargain between sovereignty principles and great power prerogatives.

While a two-house General Assembly grapples with structural questions, a third creative proposal focuses on rotating enhanced voting power.

Rotating enhanced voting power based on GDP/population over multi-year Assembly sessions distributes influence fairly across countries. This circumvents permanent hierarchy by shifting leverage periodically. However, wielding then losing status could breed resentment during transitions. Regular vote share recalculations are also required. But rotation can allow both large and small countries to periodically experience greater impact, promoting understanding between the groups.

The ongoing debate surrounding voting structure in the UN General Assembly reflects the complex balancing act inherent to any multilateral body. While the current one-country-one-vote system faces justified criticism for overrepresenting small states, moves to allocate votes purely by population or economic power risk marginalizing smaller voices. Reform proposals attempt to strike compromises but confront obstacles in both theory and practice.

On balance, a blended weighted voting approach seems among the most viable solutions despite flaws. By maintaining a standard vote per state while moderately incorporating factors like GDP and population, a blended system could help mend representational imbalances without losing the spirit of sovereign equality.

However, the challenges of transitioning from status quo cannot be underestimated. In essence, any change in the UNGA voting structure would have to be voted by UNGA itself!

Countries benefiting from current rules are unlikely to vote against their own interests. Any reform must be gradual to absorb change, but still requires grand bargains where no member feels abruptly disenfranchised. “Winners” from reform must convince “losers” that moderate change ultimately strengthens the UN, despite short-term sacrifice. Addressing concerns like rigidity and arbitrary vote thresholds in new systems can help ease doubts, and a broad feeling of shared sacrifice for the common good remains essential.

For UN member states to willingly accept voting reforms that may limit their current influence, they must figuratively get above “the machine” and adopt system-wide thinking. Essentially, we must forget about game theory and act “as if” everyone plays along nicely.

This demands dialogue, empathy, and persuasion to cultivate consensus. With realistic expectations and incremental steps, the barriers of status quo bias and national self-interest can potentially be navigated. But the challenges inherent in convincing nations to willingly cede any influence cannot be underestimated. Major reform will hinge on patiently realigning national interests with the universal ideals of the UN through trust-building and mutual understanding.

That’s a big ask.

Related Essays